Archive for October, 2010

Grad Classes in Course 14 (Part 2)

I decided to delay the posting of this Part 2 (of a two-part series) in order to get more experience in these classes. I’m currently enjoying 14.121/14.122, 14.771, and Harvard’s Market Design class (Ec 2056a). All three of my grad classes are also being taken by undergrad friends whom I work on psets with and talk to about the course material. This shared experience makes the subjects a whole lot more fun. I’ll wrap up this series by presenting my characterizations of first-year and second-year classes.

First-year classes (14.121-14.124, 14.381-14.382, 14.451-14.454) are usually described as very functional. These are “toolbox” classes meant to equip the budding economist with an arsenal for tackling problems. The core material you’re learning can be very dry, but awesome theoretical or empirical applications are not in short supply. For instance, 14.121 covered consumer theory, producer theory, aggregation, and other core micro concepts, but also featured numerous General Equilibrium applications. My favorite was the testing of an elaborate theoretical risk-sharing model with data from three poor ICRISAT villages in India.

Second-year classes offer a much more narrow, yet concentrated view of a particular field in economics. These classes inundate you with papers upon papers of studies of that particular field. If you’re truly passionate about a field of economics and feel that you can handle tons of reading, take a field class! Not only will you hone your research skills; you might also discover that idea that leads to an exciting new research project in economics.

No Comments

Why do we Procrastinate?

Lately, I’ve been thinking about why people procrastinate. Hunt Allcott, a visiting professor in the Econ Department, talked about the prevalence of procrastination in his UEA Lunch. Allcott noted that procrastination seems to occur quite frequently, and that many psychological studies have shown that people prefer to procrastinate instead of smoothing work of a certain period of time. But in theory, you would expect that people would finish a constant amount of work each day, until the task is finally completed. Thus, if you have W amount of work, and have N days until you need to complete it, you would finish W/N amount of work each day.

Obviously, this doesn’t seem to be the case empirically. People procrastinate all the time, not just about long, arduous assignments, but also about quick tasks (like doing laundry). It seems, though, that people procrastinate less for quick tasks. If something can be done in a couple minutes, people tend to get it out of the way. However, people tend to really put off longer assignments, like studying for an exam (which you could conceivably have an entire semester to study for).

I came across a paper that explained many of these phenomena. For instance, it went over why people procrastinate at all when it seems in their best interests to complete work at a steady pace. The paper creates a model that incorporates the utility derived from not working. The authors, Markus Brunnermeier, Filippos Papakonstantinou, and Jonathan Parker, posit that overconfidence in one’s own ability to do a certain task leads to incorrect planning. The authors argue that people usually only view the “best case scenario” so that people drastically overestimate their ability to quickly finish a task. However, this overconfidence actually optimizes a person’s utility function. For instance, suppose a task can be completed in two time periods. If a person procrastinates, that person will have more work in the second period, and thus have lower utility during that period. However, during the first period, one’s utility is increased by multiple distinct factors. First, the person gains utility from not actually completing the task. Second, the person gains from expecting to have little work in the second period because of overoptimism. Finally, in the first period, the person has a decrease in perceived uncertainty about the amount of work required (the person thinks he/she knows exactly how much work will be required because of his/her overoptimism). The combined effect of less actual work, less expected work, and greater certainty in the first period outweighs the added work one gains in the second period. Thus, procrastination is actually optimal in terms of maximizing a person’s utility function (the paper proves this in terms of their model in Appendix B).

This paper is exciting not just because of its conclusions, although I always have wondered why people (including me) put things off for so long, but because it also shows the enormous flexibility of economics and economic modeling in particular. One can use economic analysis to explain many different phenomena, even if they do reside in the psychological or sociological realms.

1 Comment

Economists Saving Lives (and doing other awesome stuff)

This term I am cross-registering at Harvard to take Market Design, taught by Professors Alvin Roth and Peter Coles. The class is offered jointly by the Harvard Economics Department and the Harvard Business School. I have interests in computer science and economics, and I actually first heard about market/mechanism design from the computer science literature. However, the research done in these two fields are quite different. Generally, economists are concerned about efficiency, equilibrium stability, and incentives, while computer scientists try to optimize the algorithms behind the markets.

Before I list off too many vague terms, here’s an example of market design at work:  kidney matching. Every year, more and more Americans are placed on the waitlist for transplant kidneys to replace their own failing or diseased kidneys. Thousands of people either die or become too sick to receive a transplant while waiting for a matching kidney. It is important to note is that people have two kidneys, but can lead normal lives with just one. A lot of people on the waitlist have loving relatives or friends who would donate one of their kidneys, but they unfortunately do not have the same blood types and other characteristics necessary for transplant.

Kidney exchange first came about when two relatives met at a dialysis center waiting room. They realized that the relative of one patient is a match for the other patient, and vice versa — they could swap kidney donations, and both families would be better off! Professor Roth has worked to establish databases of recipient and donor pairs, and they run a stable matching algorithm on the database every two weeks. The frequency at which we run the matching can change the number of total matches we get over time, since new patients are being added to the database and current patients can be removed for various reasons. Two weeks has just worked out well in practice.

[I actually had a problem on my 6.046 take-home exam last fall motivated by kidney matching. We were supposed to find the fastest algorithm possible to match people, given a set of donor parameters and recipient requirements -- computer science and economics working together :-) ]

Theoretically, it is possible to have longer exchange cycles than just two. (Let A1, B1 be a recipient-donor pair, A2, B2 be a second donor pair, etc, for a total of n pairs. Then we can imagine a situation where A1 can donate to B2, A2 can donate to B3, A3 can donate to B4, etc, until we loop back and An donates to Bn.) In practice — and this is also where economic incentives come in — we need to have all the operations simultaneously to make sure that all the donations actually happen. For a 2-way swap, that’s 4 simultaneous operations, requiring 4 surgical teams, 4 operating rooms, the works. Some longer chains and larger swaps have happened, but they are rare.

One of our MIT professors, Parag Pathak, was a graduate student at Harvard and has worked with Al Roth and co-authors to design allocation mechanisms for public school lotteries in New York, Boston, and San Francisco. The goal is to design the system for which it is a dominant strategy for people to submit their true preferences for schools. This removes the confusion from an important decision like choosing schools and makes the school-matching process stable and efficient.

The applications that we have discussed include job market matching, job markets for couples, and dating websites. We will have a guest speaker this week to present his findings in generalized matching and another guest speaker to talk about the shortage of IP addresses. Did you know that IP addresses were in shortage? Luckily, MIT got a lot of IP addresses way back when the internet first came about. I would just be listing off a bunch of terms if I wanted to talk about the theoretical topics in the course, so visit the course site if you’re interested (link below).

For my final project, I’m exploring the market for vacation house swaps. I just came across a news article about the Iraqi government auctions for their gas fields, though, so I might switch topics. Any suggestions for topics I should consider for my final project in market design would be appreciated.

If you’re interested in learning more about market design, here are some useful links:

Market Design blog by Al Roth and Peter Coles: http://marketdesigner.blogspot.com/

2056a course site: http://isites.harvard.edu/icb/icb.do?keyword=k72549

Al Roth’s game theory, experimental economics, and market design page: http://kuznets.fas.harvard.edu/~aroth/alroth.html

The Market Design class that I am taking (2056a in Harvard code) is a graduate course, with game theory as a prerequisite. If you are interested in taking this class, you should take game theory (e.g. 14.12) as soon as possible because 2056a and 14.12 are only offered in the fall (and also because game theory is awesome!).

I will likely blog next about Development Economics and 14.771 next, stay tuned!

No Comments

Japan’s Premium Pricing

Ever wonder why in New York, there are lines of Japanese tourists at Saks and Fifth Avenue? Or why wherever there are designer outlets, there are small middle-aged Asian women teeter-tottering from the weight of their designer haul?

The answer? Japan’s premium pricing.

When foreign goods enter Japan’s market, they become, by default, a ‘premium good’. This is the consequence of Japan’s government policy where protection tariffs increase the cost of foreign goods and informal cartels keep the pricing high. A $298 designer bag in the U.S. has a market price of $711 in Japan. However, with the advent of online auction sites and mid-street level brands like Uniqlo (which has their production site in China), Japanese consumers are becoming more and more disillusioned and dissatisfied with the high costs they price for designer goods. What will be interesting to see is if government policy will actually change or if Japanese consumers will continue to embark on ‘shopping trips’ to the U.S. and Europe for their fill of premium goods at Western market value.

Reference: Business of Fashion, “Japan’s Premium Pricing”

No Comments